1 Does Participatory Democracy Actually Deepen Democracy ...

3 downloads 132218 Views 192KB Size Report
outcomes produced by participatory institutions is best explained by ..... average best captures the degree to which the governments delegate authority.
Does Participatory Democracy Actually Deepen Democracy? Lessons from Brazil Brian Wampler [email protected], [email protected]

Abstract: This article develops an analytical framework that can be utilized to demonstrate how and where participatory institutions may contribute to the deepening of democracy. The main argument in this article is that the substantial variation in the outcomes produced by participatory institutions is best explained by identifying the incentives of elected governments to delegate authority and the capacity of civil society organizations (CSOs) to use contentious politics inside and outside of these new institutions. Participatory institutions are being advocated by the World Bank and United Nations as strategies to empower individuals, diminish corruption, and improve the quality of policy-making. This article analyzes eight cases of Brazil’s well-known Participatory Budgeting (PB) program in order to account for the wide range of outcomes produced. Two municipalities produced strong results and two other municipalities produced failed programs. Four municipalities produced PB programs with mixed, and somewhat contradictory, results. The findings suggest that failed participatory programs can have a pernicious effect on efforts to deepen democracy while the most successful programs are managing to improve the quality of local democratic processes.

This is a draft currently under review. Please do not directly cite without the author’s permission. The author gladly accepts and appreciates feedbacks, comments, and suggestions.

1

Introduction Over the past two decades participatory institutions have been initiated throughout the developing world in order to deepen the quality of democracy. Local governments in countries as diverse as Brazil, India, Venezuela, South Africa, and Indonesia have experimented with participatory institutions to promote governmental accountability, create active and knowledgeable citizens, and establish the conditions for achieving social justice (Santos 1998; Heller 2001; Fung and Wright 2003). The initial body of research on participatory democracy programs has largely extolled the positive benefits of these institutions, highlighting how participatory institutions have been able to produce specific social and political advances that deepen the quality of democracy (Abers 2001; Avritzer 2002; Baoicchi 2005; Heller 2001; Nylen 2003; Santos 2005). According to this literature, social capital is being generated, citizens are being empowered, and governments are becoming more transparent (Baoicchi 2003 and 2005; Heller 2000; Wampler and Avritzer 2004; Wampler 2004). Despite a rich literature on participatory institutions in democratizing countries, we continue to lack a coherent theoretical explanation to account for where and when these participatory experiences are likely to be successful. Institutions as diverse as the World Bank, the United Nations, Brazil’s leftist Workers’ Party, the Venezuelan government led by Hugo Chavez, and India’s Communist Party are now promoting the adoption of participatory institutions, which means that it now crucial to advance our understanding of these programs. The absence of a generalizable theoretical framework to explain the divergent outcomes produced by participatory institutions has methodological and conceptual roots.

2

Methodologically, most studies on participatory institutions are single case studies and have focused on the most successful cases (Abers 1998 and 2001, Baoicchi 2003 and 2005; Santos 2003). While these studies have greatly advanced our understanding of how participatory institutions can deepen democracy, their theoretical findings are not generalizable because they select on the dependent variable (Brady and Collier 2004). Conceptually, civil society has received the lion’s share of scholars’ attention. The role of state officials has been downplayed despite the active role they play in these participatory processes. If participatory institutions have the potential to deepen democracy, we must also recognize that they also have the potential to undermine efforts to deepen the quality of democracy. What explains why some participatory institutions succeed, some fail, and others produce mediocre results? The purpose of this article is to develop a framework to explain how actual, existing participatory democratic institutions function by analyzing the strategies and behaviors of governments and citizen-participants. The main argument is that the substantial variation in the participatory institutions’ outcomes is best explained by identifying the incentives of local governments to delegate authority, and the capacity of civil society organizations (CSOs) to use contentious politics inside and outside of new institutions. Participatory institutions complement representative democracy, which means that government officials must decide if delegating decision-making authority directly to citizens coincides with their own interests. Elected officials must determine if they can accommodate the demands presented by citizens in participatory institutions with their broader electoral, intra-party, governing, and policy interests. As governments’

3

willingness to delegate authority decreases, so too does the quality of the participatory program. When mayors are willing to delegate authority, citizens and CSOs must choose how they will make use of this new type of authority. CSOs must be willing to engage in intense cooperation with government officials; without cooperation, government officials have a diminished interest in supporting a participatory program. Yet, close cooperation can quickly led to co-optation. Thus, the presence of contentious politics provides a means for citizens to place pressure on the government that allows citizen-participants to avoid co-optation. Citizens and CSOs must be willing to publicly pressure government officials over the government’s (in) actions related to the participatory institution. In this article, I will draw from most well-known case of participatory democracy in the developing world, Brazil’s Participatory Budgeting (PB), to show how government official and citizens have managed this balancing act. I will argue that some PB programs have been managed very skillfully (most notably the famous case of Porto Alegre), which contributes to the deepening of democracay. I will also show that other PB programs have not been managed similarly, producing weak and failed outcomes. Beyond Porto Alegre’s PB, this article examines of seven additional PB programs in Brazil. This article draws upon a broad selection of scholarly works on PB as well as nearly three years of field research, a citizen-participant survey, budgetary analyses, elite interviews, and hundreds of hours of participant observations. The article proceeds in the following manner. There is first a brief overview of Participatory Budgeting (PB). This is followed by a discussion of Strong Democracy and the burgeoning literature on participatory institutions in Brazil (Barber 1984). The third

4

section develops the argument. In the fourth section, I begin by setting up a typology of four outcomes produced by the eight cases, which is followed by an analysis of the eight cases.

What is Participatory Budgeting? Brazil's federal system provides municipalities with nearly fifteen percent of all public spending (Montero 2000). This helps to explain why social movements, nongovernmental organizations, neighborhood associations, and politicians have focused so much attention on budgets at the municipal level. Brazilian mayors enjoy considerable autonomy, allowing them to initiate new programs with only minimal interference from municipal legislative chambers. Many local governments have used their relative flexibility to implement PB (Wampler and Avritzer 2005; Goldfrank forthcoming). Participatory Budgeting is a year-long decision-making process in which citizens negotiate among themselves and with government officials in organized meetings over the allocation of new capital investment spending on projects, such as health care clinics, schools, and street paving (Abers 2001; Baoicchi 2003 and 2005; Fedozzi 1998; Nylen 2003; Wampler and Avritzer 2004). In the more successful cases, citizens have the authority to make policy decisions, which has the potential to alter the basic decisionmaking process in Brazilian politics. Citizens are mobilized to attend meetings during which they vote for public policies and elected community representatives. PB programs combine elements of direct (i.e. direct mobilization of citizens in decision-making venues) and representative (i.e. electing representatives) democracy. These programs also pay increased attention to transparency and social justice, both of which are designed to

5

change how local governments in Brazil have long functioned, which is often described as clientelistic and personalistic (Avritzer 2002; Baierle 1998; Avritzer and Navarro 2003). Research has demonstrated that the majority of PB participants and PB delegates are low income and have low levels of education (Baiocchi 2001; Nylen 2003; Wampler 2007). This means that when PB programs produce positive outcomes, they are most intensely affecting individuals from historically excluded groups. PB programs have not successfully incorporated middle and upper income individuals and groups, because PB’s rules favor low-income neighborhoods by rewarding greater levels of resources on a per capita basis to poorer and more densely populated neighborhoods. PB was initially part of a broader transformative political project that the Workers’ Party (PT) leadership believed would help create new types of citizens as well as transform state-society relations by delegating authority to citizens (Genro 1995 and 1997; Nylen 2002). While the broader transformations have not yet materialized, PB has been recognized as helping to overhaul how municipal governments function, becoming one element of reform packages associated with “good government” (Hunter 2004; Guidry 2003; Wampler and Avritzer 2005). Participatory Budgeting programs received international attention when the United Nations named this institutional type one of the best 40 practices at the 1996 Istanbul Habitat Conference.

Participatory Democracy Benjamin Barber’s Strong Democracy: Participatory Politics for a New Age calls for citizens and government officials to design institutions that will directly incorporate

6

citizens into decision-making venues (Barber 1984). Barber asserts that a fundamental problem of actual, existing liberal democracy is the lack of active participation. While Barber fretted about the lack of institutional innovation and re-design in the United States, Barber’s call for Strong Democracy has been followed in developing world democracies as reformers sought to overcome limitations associated with that of representative democracy. Barber lays out several basic criteria that would allow for the “viability and practicality as well as to the coherence of the theory” of Strong Democracy (Barber 1984: 262). Participatory institutions should: be realistic and workable. For all practical purposes, this means that they ought to be a product of actual political experience. complement and be compatible with the primary representative institutions of large-scale modern societies. directly address liberal anxieties over such unitary propensities of participatory communities as irrationalism, prejudice, uniformity, and intolerance. deal concretely with the obstacles that modernity appears to place in the way of participation: namely, scale, technology, complexity, and the paradox of parochialism. give expression to the special claims of strong democracy as a theory of talk, judgment, and public seeing by offering alternatives to representation, simple voting, and the rule of bureaucrats and experts. (Barber 1984: 262). PB’s basic set of rules meet Barber’s basic definitions for Strong Democracy. PB is an institution that emerged from direct negotiations between government officials and civil society leaders, as they sought to produce practical solutions to pressing needs (Abers 2001; Avritzer 2002; Fedozzi 1998). PB programs are housed within the mayoral administration and complement the legal and political responsibilities of mayors and municipal legislators. PB provides multiple opportunities for citizens to debate and vote

7

on projects specific to their neighborhood and to the city more generally; citizens are also encouraged to form solidarity packs with other citizens and groups (Abers 2001; Baiocchi 2005, Nylen 2003; Avritzer 2002). Finally, PB is a fairly complex decision-making process that allows for the inclusion of information about the viability of proposed policies (Wampler and Avritzer 2004).

Theoretical debate on Participatory Budgeting (PB) Researchers have proposed a range of explanations for PB outcomes, which I will briefly discuss. Each of the works cited below has made a significant contribution to advancing our understanding of this pioneering participatory experience, but they are limited by their inability to simultaneously consider the interests of the govermnent and CSOs. First, Abers’ pioneering work on PB asserts that there is a “synergy” between governments and interested citizens in Porto Alegre, which helps to create the conditions for the expansion of civil society (Abers 2001). According to Abers, PB represents a clear effort of the local state to deepen the density of CSOs by encouraging them to work in participatory decision-making venues. The state and citizens cooperate to build a broader civil society, which then helps to improve the quality of Porto Alegre’s democracy. The principal drawback to Abers’ approach is that she doesn’t explain why a government would be interested in promoting PB. The government is treated as if it was a benevolent actor, seemingly above the fray of politics and mainly interested in improving the quality of political life. Furthermore, Abers does not adequately capture the tensions and

8

conflicts within PB, as she emphasizes the cooperation among government officials and citizens. Baiocchi’s 2005 book, Militants and Citizens, draws from two years of fieldwork in three of Porto Alegre’s regional districts. This sociological treatment does an excellent job of showing how deliberative decision-making venues are constructed in a contested political arena. Conflict and tension are present in the analysis, as is close cooperation between government officials and participating citizens. Yet, the interests of the government, the politicians, and political parties are absent from the analysis. Quite simply, it is unclear from the analysis why government officials support PB. Baiocchi’s work helps to show how and why individuals and groups engage in both cooperation and contestation, but, again, the clear drawback to his work is that the government is seemingly above the political fray. Wampler and Avritzer argue that PB programs developed in the context of “participatory publics” in civil society. During the 1980s and 1990s, citizens created new organizations in which they sought to limit the pernicious effects that clientelism often has on localized and low-income groups. Many groups sought to organize themselves internally in more democratic fashions in order to exert more influence over state affairs and to create a vibrant and more inclusive public sphere (Wampler and Avritzer 2004). There was a strong emphasis on deliberation, public votes, and transparency. Institutional innovations were then incorporated into state-sanctioned institutions, such as PB as CSO activists and reformed-minded politicians sought to transform basic state-society relationships by overhauling state institutions. However, the drawback to this approach is

9

that it, like Aber and Baiocchi, provides few clues about why governments would be willing to delegate authority to citizens. Goldfrank, in a comparative analysis of participatory programs in Caracas, Montevideo, and Porto Alegre argues that outcomes are best explained by the interaction of two factors: The degree of decentralization afforded to municipal governments by the national state and the degree of party institutionalization (Goldfrank, forthcoming). With regard to decentralization, Goldfrank finds that greater levels of authority given to mayors will result in stronger outcomes. In the eight Brazilian municipalities studied here, the degree of authority afforded to mayors is held largely constant, which means that the degree of decentralization cannot explain different outcomes among Brazilian municipalities. With regard to party institutionalization, Goldfrank finds that strongly institutionalized party systems have a limiting impact on the participatory institutions. Entrenched political parties are unwilling to support innovation. Conceptually, this argument marks an important turn in the debate, as it moves us away from a narrow focus on civil society to a broader focus on the interests of government officials. However, this approach still does not adequately explain why specific governments would be willing to delegate authority to citizens. The scholarly debates on PB have therefore emphasized how civil society has been transformed, why civil society organizations support PB, and why some specific political moments are conducive to initiating participatory democracy. Yet, little is written about the political interests of the governments, which is at the center of this analysis.

10

The Argument: Explaining Outcomes The two most important factors that account for the wide variation in PB outcomes are the level of mayoral support for the delegation of authority directly to citizens and the types and range of political activities utilized by CSOs. In order to produce a strong PB program, it is necessary to have high levels of mayoral support for delegation and a civil society that can engage in both cooperation and contentious politics. As mayoral support drops, and as CSOs are unable to engage in both forms of political behavior, PB outcomes weaken. These two factors interact: An increase in contentious politics by CSOs often leads governments to delegate additional authority and resources but there is also the ever-present possibility that too much contestation will lead to a decrease in mayoral support. There are three factors that have an important effect but will not be discussed in this analysis: mayoral-legislative relations, PB’s rules, and the resources available in the budget for new capital investments.

Mayoral support Strong mayoral support is vital to produce successful PB outcomes because mayoral administrations initiate and administrator PB. Mayors must make a series of very specific decisions regarding the degree of authority that they are willing to delegate; key decision-makers within the mayoral administration must be willing to spend scarce resources on projects selected by citizens. In Brazil, the implementation of “new capital investment” spending, which is the principal focus of PB programs, is at the complete discretion of the mayor’s office.1

11

While PB is a form of participatory democracy with direct and representative elements, it is also falls within Brazil’s historical legacy of mayoral domination of municipal agenda-setting (Nunes 1997). Ironically, mayors must first centralize authority in their own hands before they can hand the authority back over to citizens via PB. For PB to work well, mayors need to decentralize the administration, create internal procedures to prepare information to allow citizens to make sense of complex policy issues, re-train staff and bureaucrats to work directly with citizens, and, perhaps most importantly, transform the process through which projects are “green lighted” towards implementation. If a mayor is unable to gain control over the bureaucracy, or his/her own political appointees, then it is not likely that a mayor will be able to delegate authority. Why do some mayors delegate authority? First, mayors delegate authority to citizens in new participatory institutions as a means to reach out to their municipality’s most active CSO participants/leaders and to encourage the formation of new CSOs that may become part of the government’s base of support. Through PB, mayors have direct access to community leaders, which means that PB serves as a potential recruitment site as well as a forum for government officials to discover community’s most pressing problems. PB allows the mayoral administration to reach out to citizens and CSO activists who were not initially part of the mayor’s political coalition. Elections are held every two years in Brazil. Presidential, gubernatorial and state and federal legislative elections are held at the same time (1994, 1998, 2002, 2006), while mayoral and municipal legislative contests are held in the “mid-term” years time (1996, 2000, 2004). Federal senatorial elections may occur in either election cycle. Therefore, mayors and municipal legislators are nearly constantly campaigning, which means that

12

PB not only provides mayors with an opportunity to have close and constant access to the most active CSO leaders, but it also allows the mayors to identify which CSO leaders do the best job at turning out their supporters. This is crucial information for politicians as they can more readily identify who they should hire for their electoral campaigns. A second reason that mayors delegate authority is to reward their most loyal supporters. In Brazil, CSO activists who work on behalf of leftist political parties have demanded, since the late 1980s, that ordinary citizens be directly involved in decisionmaking venues. PB provides a means for government officials to allow their political base to “practice democracy” by having a direct role in governmental decision-making. The political base is able to exercise “voice and vote” in a state institution, thereby satisfying the basic demands of citizens to be directly involved. PB provides an opportunity for ordinary party members to practice and be engaged in democratic processes at the local level. The third factor that helps to explain mayoral delegation is party politics. The political party that has most strongly advocated PB is the leftist (sometime socialist) Workers’ Party (PT). With only one exception, all PT mayoral administrations in large municipalities (more than 100,000 residents) implemented some form of PB between 1989 and 2004 (Wampler and Avritzer 2005).2 PT mayors have been induced to adopt PB to adhere to the “PT way of governing,” which involves the direct incorporation of citizens in public policy decision-making venues, an emphasis on social justice, and an effort to enhance transparency (Hunter 2004; Guidry 2003). However, the PT is sufficiently decentralized that the national leadership does not attempt to verify that their local governments dedicate the necessary time, energy, and resources to ensure the PB

13

will function well. The PT sought to “brand” itself as a reformist political party, which is why the party emphasized PB’s transparency, social justice, and deliberative components. Finally, there is a generational component. The political leadership that came of age during the mobilized opposition to Brazils military government in the 1970s and1980s strongly supported the direct incorporation of citizens in order to “empower” citizens and to transform how the Brazilian state functioned (Villas Boas and Telles 1995; Genro 1995 and 1997). The ideological composition of the mayor and his/her closest advisors strongly conditions the extent to which mayors will be partially willing to gamble their political future on the delegation of authority directly to citizens. Therefore, part of PB’s original success is linked to ideological formation of a new political elite during the transition to democratic rule, which means that it will be increasingly less likely that new, younger mayors will be willing to delegate authority to citizens.

Type of Civil Society Activity: Cooperation and Contestation How do CSOs and individual citizens act inside and outside of PB? What strategies do they pursue vis-à-vis government officials and their fellow participants? CSOs and individual citizens must be willing to cooperate in a government-sponsored program while also being able, when necessary, to engage in contentious behavior (Tarrow 1998; McAdams, Tarrow and Tilly 2001). Cooperation and contestation are both needed since there are deliberative and competitive decision-making components to PB. Citizens must cooperate closely with government officials in order to gain access to technical, legislative, and budgetary information. Participants must be willing to

14

cooperate with the government and their fellow participants in order to facilitate meetings and negotiation. For example, if civil society groups are bitter rivals and unable to agree on seemingly simple matters such as a meeting format, then PB will weaken because it is no longer a deliberative space focused on a broader set of problems, but instead becomes a political space that rival groups try to occupy and control. The cooperation that is a necessary part of PB can easily breed co-optation. Contentious politics gives CSOs the opportunity to vigorously defend their projects in the face of governmental doubts and potential indifference, which helps CSOs and activists avoid co-optation. The use of contentious politics is more likely in urban settings where there is a large plurality of organizations (safety in numbers), where citizens and civil society organizations can appeal to different political parties (competition), where there is a social and historical tradition of using direct action against governments and private businesses, and where the leadership of the party overseeing PB makes it clear that they will not penalize citizens and CSOs that use contentious politics. First, a broad plurality of CSOs enables the use of cooperation and contestation because a broader number of CSOs (higher density), with diverse sets of interests, makes the cost of co-optation for the government higher. Simultaneously, CSOs have a lower fear of reprisal because the government has a more difficult time punishing deviant groups. Density, therefore, is important because of the benefits that it provides to CSOs as they decide on the appropriate course of action. Second, when multiple political parties vie for the support of CSOs and when CSOs are willing to align themselves with a broader range of parties, CSOs are able increase their demands. CSOs may be able to negotiate with multiple politicians rather than a narrow set of ideological partners.

15

However, in a highly competitive party system, government officials may also bring direct pressure to bear on CSOs to ensure that contentious politics is not used in a way that would embarrass the government, which thereby limits the political strategies available to CSOs. Third, a history of contentious politics in a municipality appears to makes it easier for currently active CSOs to use direct confrontation inside and outside of the participatory institution. Contentious behavior is therefore not viewed as exceptional behavior, but as a legitimate means for citizens and CSOs to express their political voice. Finally, when government officials do not punish CSOs for using contentious politics there is a greater likelihood that CSOs will be willing to directly confront government officials inside and outside of PB. Conversely, when CSOs are discouraged from using contentious forms of politics, especially when these had previously been part of their repertoire of actions, then there will likely be a decrease in support for the participatory institution.

Eight Brazilian cases of Participatory Budgeting Figure 1, below, is a typology of four outcomes that have been produced by PB programs. The two main components of the argument, the use of contentious politics by CSOs and mayoral support for delegation, form the basis for the comparison. To illustrate the level of mayoral support and the presence/absence of contentious politics, several different measures are used. First, I draw from a survey (n=695) of PB delegates in these eight municipalities, which tapped into citizens’ attitudes on their ability to exercise authority within PB programs. I present the averaged results of six questions related to

16

authority. Second, I use the percentage of new capital investment spending that the government allows the delegates to negotiate between 2001 and 2003, which helps to demonstrate the extent to which government officials are willing to hand one type of authority (budgetary authority) to citizens. There are yearly fluctuations so a three-year average best captures the degree to which the governments delegate authority. I also draw from participant-observation and more than 150 interviews over an eight-year period (1996-2004) to establish the basis for assessing mayoral support and the presence of contentious politics. Figure 1 Participatory Democracy Outcomes Use of Contentious Politics by CSOs High High Mayoral Support for Delegation Of Authority To Citizens Medium

Low

Institutionalized Participatory Democracy

Porto Alegre Ipatinga

N/A

Informal and Contested Participatory Democracy

Co-opted Participatory Democracy

Recife Belo Horizonte

Santo André São Paulo Emasculated Participatory Democracy

N/A Low

Blumenau Rio Claro

Institutionalized Participatory Democracy

17

The box in the top left includes the most successful cases, Porto Alegre and Ipatinga. Institutionalized participatory democracy refers to a decision-making process in which citizens have the authority to make specific binding decisions regarding how the government will act. Citizens carefully study the rules, which can only be modified by a citizens’ oversight committee, in order to pursue their private/particularistic interests and contribute to the broader debates of the community. The government oversees or manages the participatory institution and follows the rules, both in spirit and in practice. The rules are well-known to all and are followed. Citizens are willing and able to use contentious politics outside of PB, as a means to pressure legislators and media representatives, but they were also able to use contentious politics inside of PB as a means to pressure their government to act (Baiocchi 2005). Porto Alegre is widely considered to be the most successful case of PB and has been widely studied (Abers 1998 and 2001; Baoicchi 2003 and 2005; Fedozzi 1998). In Porto Alegre, the PT won the 1988 mayoral election with just 35% of the vote. The new government worked closely with an umbrella CSO and its own party activists to develop the basic set of rules associated with PB (Abers 2001; Baierle 1998; Wampler and Avritzer 2004). There was very strong support from PT members and civil society activists to reform the very nature of the state by investing heavily in PB. In Ipatinga, the PT also won the 1988 mayoral election and began to implement participatory forms of politics in 1989. The PT’s base of support was firmly located in leftist and PT-oriented labor unions. However, Ipatinga’s delgates did not have direct control over decision-making until 1997 because the government was initially unwilling to delegate any substantial levels of authority directly to citizens. In 1997, the

18

government slowly increased the level of authority they delegated because the mayor realized that it was a beneficial political and governing strategy.3 Porto Alegre grew from a small number of participants, just 976 in 1990, to an average of 31,000 a year between 2001 and 2004.4 The PT-led government invested heavily in turning individuals out to participate (Abers 2001; Baiocchi 2005). PB became a crucial base of support to the PT as the party’s candidates won mayoral elections in 1992, 1996, 2000, and the state’s governor’s office in 1998. The institutional design of PB fosters deliberation and has a strong emphasis on social justice, which allowed the main themes of the PT to be prominently featured. Since the government successfully implemented a broad number of PB projects, there was a positive reinforcement associated with PB (Goldfrank and Schneider 2003; Wampler 2004). In Porto Alegre, 100% of new capital investment funds were decided by delegates (Wampler and Avritzer 2004). As a result of the strong support by the government for PB, in Porto Alegre, 72% of the survey respondents say that they are “always” or “almost always,” able to exercise authority.5 Since the majority of the survey respondents are low income, this suggests that authority is being transferred to representatives of Brazil’s historically excluded and marginalized lower classes. Ipatinga’s government has never able to count on a large turn-out of its citizens, although they did grow from several hundred participants in the early 1990s to over 5,000 by 2002. Ipatinga’s PB is based on a dual-track system in which 50% of new capital investment funds were directly decided by citizens. Citizens select projects that the government agrees to implement if they are able to secure external funding. The government annually seeks state and federal funds to complement the new capital

19

investment funds, which means that between 60-75% of new capital investment funds were decided by citizens in PB forums. In Ipatinga, 64% of the respondents say that they are “always” or “almost always” able to exercise authority, which is weaker than Porto Alegre, reflecting the fact that Ipatinga’s PB participants could negotiate over a smaller percentage of resources. The PT governments in Porto Alegre and Ipatinga were first elected in 1989, during a moment of political renewal in Brazil. Both elected governments were led by political outsiders who sought to overhaul state-society relations, create a new path towards socialism, and empower citizens (Fedozzi 1998; Genro 1997; Santos 1998). Therefore, an important part of Porto Alegre’s and Ipatinga’s PB successes has been the presence of leadership that was ideologically committed to revamping the municipality’s basic decision-making processes. The ideological commitment among the leadership includes support for the active use of contentious politics. The local PT leadership in both municipalities came of age politically as members of opposition to the military regime (1964) and were well versed in the use of contentious politics. In Porto Alegre, throughout the 1990s, PB participants engaged in contentious politics against opposition legislators and media outlets at key events such as the World Social Forum. Importantly, PB meetings also have basic aspects of contentious politics as citizens regularly denounced and criticized the government for incompetence or indifference. The government did not dampen the debate, but allowed for the development of free-flowing accountability sessions. The high levels of mayoral support has helped to institutionalize participatory democracy in Porto Alegre and Ipatinga, while the active use of contentious politics by

20

CSOs and citizens allows them to avoid co-optation. These two cases are successful because government officials and citizens pursue their interests within the new institution. Government officials don’t bypass the rules and citizens were rewarded for their efforts to work within the new rules. This represents a significant change in local politics in Brazil, where the rules are often manipulated by officeholders. Citizens were able to use contentious politics inside and outside of PB to pressure government officials to adhere to the basic rules of the game.

Emasculated Participatory Democracy The bottom-right box, “Emasculated Participatory Democracy,” includes the least successful cases, Blumenau and Rio Claro. In neither case has the government supported participatory democratic processes. In neither case have citizens been able to use contentious politics inside or outside of PB to press their claims. Blumenau has a very dense civil society, with high levels of participation in its PB, but political accommodation is the preferred method of reaching political decisions (Andrade 1996 and 2000). In Rio Claro, civil society has very low density and its leaders are unwilling to risk their already weak influence on the mayoral administration to demand a more expansive PB (Teixeira and Alburquque 2005). Neither mayoral administration was deeply invested in PB, and the lack of pressure from civil society organizations neutered the programs. If there is no pressure emanating from civil society, then there is no need to expand the level of authority delegated to citizens. In Blumenau, the Workers’ Party (PT) government initiated PB in 1997 at the behest of two groups: A political group affiliated with the local university and

21

progressive CSOs that had ties to similar organizations in municipalities that already had PB or similar participatory programs (Andrade 1996 and 2000; Rolim 2001). PB was implemented to satisfy these groups and to allow them to practice the participatory democracy that the PT had preached for so long. However, these groups were not central to the mayor’s political base. Thus, with regard to the first criteria of using PB as a means to reach out to the government’s own base of activists, there were few incentives for the government to delegate authority. In Rio Claro, a Green Party mayor initiated PB at the behest of one faction of his government and as means to reach out to middle class voters (Texeira and Alburquque 2005). However, the main base of support of the mayor was located within the Green Party, which emphasized innovative policies designed by technical experts that would solve pressing agricultural and environmental problems. Second, both governments had low interest in using PB as a means to establish a supportive and mobilized voting base, although this lack of interest stemmed from very different reasons. Blumenau had high rates of participation, with nearly 10% of the adult population participating, which should have meant that the mayor would see the opportunity and invest heavily in rewarding citizen’s choices. However, opposition politicians (most notably, the PFL, a conservative, neo-liberal party) captured control over nearly half of the regional districts.6 Thus, it was not in the government’s interest to delegate decision-making authority to a participatory institution that was partially captured by political opponents. In Rio Claro, there was a weak civil society and people participated in very low numbers. The government did not have an incentive to deepen its commitment to a participatory policy-making program that was poorly attended. Less than one percent of

22

citizens attended meetings in any given year. Furthermore, the meetings were dominated by government officials, which led citizens to believe that their participation would not affect outcomes (Teixeira and Alburqueque 2005). In Blumenau, the mayor allowed citizens to negotiate roughly 15% of new capital investment spending.7 In Rio Claro, the mayor allowed citizens to negotiate less than 10% of new capital investment spending.8 These figures suggest that the mayors were not interested in taking the political risk necessary to create vibrant PB programs. In Rio Claro just 20% of the survey respondents declaring that they are “always” or “almost always” able to exercise authority. Blumenau was a bit better, as 38% of the respondents say that they are able, “always” or “almost always,” to exercise authority. In Blumenau, the PT government that governed between 1997 and 2004 was not driven by an ideological commitment to re-shape Brazilian politics and society by directly incorporating citizens into key decision-making processes. Rather, the government had been elected at a period of economic down-turn, a corruption scandal among Blumenau’s leading politicians, and a split driven by personal factors among the municipality’s two principal parties. The PT government had no mandate to embark on serious reform. Thus, they produced an emasculated participatory program. In Rio Claro, the government has also not been dedicated to a reversal of basic decision-making processes. The government’s principal interest has focused on revising public policy processes that would include policy innovations, rather than relying on citizens to be actively involved in decision-making. Of course, citizens and CSOs in Blumenau and Rio Claro could have led protests against the government to pressure them to focus more energy, time, and resources on

23

PB. In Blumenau, however, there is no tradition of direct contestation and confrontation. Blumeanu has a dense civil society, but it is based on the politics of accommodation rather than confrontation. CSOs received a series of benefits from the government outside of PB, so they were unwilling to directly confront the government over PB’s failings (Souza 2003). Blumenau’s PB program failed because the government lacked any substantial interest in promoting it as a new institutional decision-making venue and citizen-participants had little interest or leverage in trying to pressure the government to make PB the center of a new governing arrangement. In Rio Claro, too, there was not a history of contentious politics (Teixeira and Albuquerque 2005). Union activity began in the 1930s when Rio Claro became a major railroad stop, but politics was based on accommodation and compromise rather than contentious politics. The combination of low density and the lack of contentious politics have created an unsuccessful PB programs. “No contestation, no delegation.” This is key lesson to be drawn from the experiences of Rio Claro and Blumenau. Without contestation, it is impossible to use PB as a means to deepen democracy. The low levels of mayoral support for the delegation of authority neutered the PB programs in Rio Claro and Blumenau. CSOs and citizens were unwilling (Blumenau) or unable (Rio Claro) to rely on contentious politics to pressure the government to dedicate more time, energy, and resources to PB. There was little cost to the mayors to ignore an institution that their administrations had initiated. The overall effect of PB was therefore negative because the most active CSOs leaders invested a considerable amount of time and energy in PB only to have to government brush aside their political efforts. This has obvious negative consequences for local democratic

24

processes because the emasculated participatory programs undermined the efforts of the activists who were working to deepen the quality of democracy.

Co-opted Participatory Democracy The middle right box, co-opted participatory democracy, has two cases, São Paulo and Santo André, where the mayoral administrations sought to use PB as a means to increase their direct influence over CSOs and citizen-participants. Contentious politics were discouraged; both governments engaged in strategies that effectively co-opted participants. The PT governments, in both municipalities, placed the politics of partybuilding and governance ahead of the interests of building a vibrant participatory institution. Santo André’s PB was established in 1989 with a very different rule set from most other PB programs. In Santo André there was initially strong mayoral support for PB (Pontual 2000). However, the electoral interests of PT government trumped PB as government officials were unwilling to risk their re-elections based on the interests of PB participants. According to Teresa Santos, who directed PB from 1989-1992, “some of the department heads emphasized their own projects and did not implement the projects supported by the government.”9 CSOs were incorporated into PB but discouraged from taking actions that would not promote the PT’s larger project of winning São Paulo’s gubernatorial and Brazil’s presidential elections. Santo André has a unique rule structure that increased the government’s direct control over PB participants (Daniel 2003). Their PB had a 52-member council comprised of 26 government officials and 26 elected citizens. This council had the responsibility of making a broader range of decisions; the

25

logic behind the program was “co-administration” in which citizens and government officials would be jointly responsible for making policy decisions. This was an ambitious attempt to directly incorporate the most active civil society leaders and lower level PT officials into the governmental decision-making venues. In Santo André, elected PB delegates were, at least theoretically, given control of well over half of new capital investment spending, but the institutional rules were written in such a way that the government had a veto over all policy choices. Beginning in 1997, there was a shift in logic. The PT government decreased the degree of authority allocated to citizens via PB. During the 1997-2000 period, Santo André’s mayor initiated a series of other participatory programs, which had the net effect of limiting the importance of PB because the type of decision-making authority in PB was reduced to the negotiations over small projects. Instead of emphasizing radical change, the PT began to use Santo André as a base from which they could strengthen the PT. The government did not need to rely on PB as means to attract a base of support in Santo André because they won in 62 and 70 percent, respectively, of the first round mayoral vote in 1996 and 2000. Just under half of Santo André’s respondents (46%) state that they are able, “always” or “almost always,” to exercise authority. While their authority was more limited than in Porto Alegre or Ipatinga, it was more robust than in Rio Claro or Blumenau. The relatively strong results (46%) reflect the fact that PB represents a new way of conducting politics in Brazil. Citizens have “voice and vote” in public decisionmaking venues.

26

In São Paulo, the government supported the delegation of authority to citizens, but entirely on the terms dictated by the government (Wampler 2005). PB participants were unable to successfully contest the policy choices of the government for two fundamental reasons. First, the government was in an intense political struggle to help elect the PT’s presidential candidate in 2002. São Paulo’s PB delegates were encouraged to subsume their demands under the needs of party elites. This meant that CSOs had to decide if their long-term political interests coincided with the political interests of the incumbent party. Second, the mayor’s broader set of social policies were widely supported by PB participants and social movement leaders, which has meant that they are unwilling to directly challenge the government. When the PT won the mayor’s office in São Paulo in 2000, the political group around Mayor Marta Suplicy had very weak links to participatory forms of decisionmaking. A small, left-wing faction within the PT spent its internal political capital to ensure that Suplicy would implement PB. São Paulo’s PB was not used as a tool to build a new base of support for the PT, but rather just one faction of the PT envisioned PB as a means to build the party. PB activists were not encouraged to use it a political space to transform decision-making. In São Paulo, citizens were able to negotiate roughly 25-35% of new capital investments between 2001-2004 (Wampler 2005). Authority was only partially extended to citizens because the mayor was unwilling to risk her political futures on one particular policy type. As might be expected, just under half of the respondents (49%) say that they are able, “always” or “almost always,” to exercise authority. Mayors delegated lower

27

levels of authority than in Porto Alegre and Ipatinga, which is reflected in the attitudes of the survey respondents. Santo André has a long history of union and social movement organizing, which could have created the conditions for the use of contentious politics by citizens in order to maintain a robust PB. Instead of contentious politics, Santo Andre’s government was able to co-opt citizens. How so? The emphasis on “co-administration” led the government to work closely with citizens, and the rules gave the government a veto over citizens’ decisions. In order to get projects included in the government, citizens had to align themselves with the government. Second, Santo André’s PB became part of a small means to a greater end: Civil society activists did not want to embarrass the PT because there were larger political issues at stake, namely the 1998 and 2002 gubernatorial and presidential elections. The shared set of interests among activists and government officials allowed the government to slowly withdraw support from PB without suffering negative electoral outcomes. The mayor of Santo André was closely aligned with future President Lula da Silva and the PT used their control of the government of Santo André as a base from which they could run other elections. São Paulo, too, has a long history of contentious politics. There were considerable public demonstrations against the military regimes throughout the 1960s, 1970s, and 1980s. Yet, contentious politics did not occupy a central place in and around São Paulo’s PB. The government discouraged contentious politics because they were working to establish the necessary political momentum to re-elect Mayor Marta Suplicy (she was not re-elected). To illustrate this point, the arguments of a government official and an elected representative are telling.

28

In a meeting on October 10, 2003, the PB administrator, Felix Sanchez, grew increasingly upset as PB delegates leveled a series of complaints and accusations based on the government’s weak support of PB. Sanchez sharply rebuked the PB delegates’ criticisms of PB, declaring that “no party has ever done more for São Paulo than the PT.” Sanchez yelled and berated the PB councilors who “dared” to criticize the hard work of the administration, thereby linking the party (PT) directly to the program (PB). It was a stunning display that indicated that contentious politics within PB would not be tolerated. Co-operation was emphasized, which came to mean that the government dominated PB. PB delegates were aware of the larger political issues as the 2002 and 2004 elections came up repeatedly during focus groups and informal conversations. Many delegates believed that they shouldn’t take action that might be detrimental to Mayor Suplicy. As one delegate stated, “Look, we think that PB is the best thing that has happened to us. We can participate. We are learning how to do this. But, we must re-elect Marta [Mayor Suplicy]. There are many other programs that we would lose if she loses.”10 Delegates were unwilling to publicly pressure Mayor Suplicy because of the potential negative consequences, which may have helped the mayor politically but also had the effect of weakening PB. PB delegates ceded one of their few extra-institutional sources of influence in order to help the PT politically. The PT governments in São Paulo and Santo André managed PB programs that were ostensibly crafted to directly incorporate citizens into a participatory decisionmaking venue. However, neither government was willing to delegate authority to citizens and both governments dominated the participatory processes. Instead of delegating decision-making authority directly to citizens, PB became a vehicle for both governments

29

to work with the most active participants to build the PT and to improve their electoral results. CSO leaders were discouraged from entering into direct conflict with the government, and government officials were quick to remind the participants how much the government had done for them. Winning elections, rather than participatory decisionmaking, became a central issue of both governments’ agendas. The process of co-optation has obvious negative influences for efforts to deepen the quality of democracy. The most active citizens were drawn out of their community organizations and into the political party agenda of the PT, thereby creating a leadership and representative vacuum at the neighborhood and community level. The interests of CSOs and citizens became secondary to the electoral interests of the incumbent parties. This has a contradictory effect on the deepening of democracy. Citizens and CSOs are able to express their “voice” in a state-sanctioned public institution, which is a noteworthy advance. However, participants’ demands were ultimately secondary to the government’s electoral interests, which increases the risk that the most active members of civil society will become disenchanted with working within institutionalized political structures.

Informal and Contested Participatory Democracy The middle-left box, informal and contested participatory democracy, includes two municipalities, Recife and Belo Horizonte. These governments are noteworthy for wide fluctuations in the level of mayoral support for PB. Recife and Belo Horizonte’s PB is characterized as “informal and contested” because there is a high degree of informality in how the government operates PB as well as how the government responds to

30

pressures/demands from the public. CSOs and citizens are able to pressure the government outside of the formal confines of PB, making effective use of mobilizations to draw the attention of the government back to PB programs. The governments in Recife and Belo Horizonte are unable to control CSOs that choose to participate. Belo Horizonte’s PB was initiated in 1993 by a PT mayor. The PT handily won the 1992 election and the PT was led by a group of reformers committed to overhauling basic decision-making processes in Brazil’s third largest city. The government initiated a PB program that emphasized inclusion, access, and the direct involvement of citizens in key decision-making venues. The PT government used PB as a way to reach out to CSOs’ leadership, their party’s base as well as to build a base of support among potential supporters. In Belo Horizonte, there has been rotating leadership at the top levels of the government. The PT’s coalition partner, the Brazilian Socialist Party (PSB) held the mayor’s office from 1997 through 2002, when a PT mayor returned to office. The PSB mayor and the second PT mayor dedicated fewer resources and less time, energy and political will to supporting PB. There was a decrease to 17% from 33% of the new capital investment funds that were negotiated in PB over the 1997-2003 period. Half of the respondents (50%) say that they are “always” or “almost always” able to exercise authority, which again demonstrates relatively strong support for the role that citizens are able to play in the new institutional format. In Recife, mayoral support has been as low as in the cases of Rio Claro and Blumenau, but it is has also been as high as the level in Ipatinga. Recife’s PB was initiated in 1994 by a charismatic mayor who was then a member of the catch-all Brazilian Democratic Movement Party (PMDB). This mayor had initiated participatory

31

reforms during his first term in office (1986-1988) (Soares 1998). Recife’s PB was then overseen by a conservative mayor (1997-2000), who formally maintained PB due to an electoral alliance that had been fashioned with the first mayor. In 2001, a PT mayor assumed office and dedicated increased resources, time, and energy to PB. In Recife, the first mayor dedicated just 10% of new capital investment spending to PB, although he did manage to implement 86% of the projects (1996). Between 1996 and 2000, delegates were able to negotiate 10% of new capital investment spending, but few projects were actually implemented. In 2001, the new PT mayor increased the amount of resources that could be negotiated to nearly 100% of new capital investment spending but there is no clear record if the government has been able to implement these programs. Just under half of the respondents (46%) say that they are able, “always” or “almost always,” to exercise authority. The fluctuations in resources dedicated to PB led to considerable institutional instability because it was not clear, from year to year, to participants and government bureaucrats if the participatory process would be valued by the mayoral administration or if it would be side-lined. In Belo Horizonte, the government consistently sought to “improve” PB by adopting new rules nearly every year, which created substantial confusion among CSOs and citizens as they tried to design their most optimal strategies for securing resources. The government did not have a clear system in place to move projects from the selection to implementation phase, which created an informality in the policy process. This informality combined with shifting interests of the government led to the active use of contentious politics inside and outside of PB. Contentious politics then led to increased informality as the government sought to respond to crisis by implementing projects of the

32

groups that were able to engage in contentious politics. Groups that were too small or were unable to pressure the government via contentious politics had a more difficult time receiving the public goods that they had worked hard to secure during the negotiation phase. Contentious politics were present in Recife’s and Belo Horizonte’s PB as citizens directly confronted government officials over problems associated with PB. Government officials did not retaliate against these citizens nor did they attempt to dampen discussions. In Recife, there is strong electoral competition between two political parties for the CSOs’ support. Protests and public demonstrations had to be addressed by government officials because there was a real risk that the CSO will withdraw their support for the party in power and support the opposition party. In Belo Horizonte, there is a different logic at play. The PT, which oversees its PB, is the largest party in Belo Horizonte. It is also has the strongest ties to CSOs. The party leadership, however, does not face as intense threat from rival parties as in São Paulo or Santo André, which means that CSOs are willing to use contentious politics as a way to get the government’s attention. The use of extra-institutional protests leads the governments to privilege the projects of the most active CSOs to ensure that there is not wide-spread dissatisfaction among the most active and organized members of political society. Outside of PB organized meetings, CSOs and citizens organized rallies to place pressure on the government. For example, in Belo Horizonte, in March 2004, one CSO led a mock funeral in which they symbolically buried PB. Importantly, they also threatened to block a six-lane avenue during rush hour, which would have snarled traffic for hours. This direct action was successful as the government agreed to their major

33

demands. This action sent signals to citizens throughout Belo Horizonte that direct action outside of PB was a viable strategy to secure policy outputs, which then makes PB a more ad hoc process. Instead of internal debates and negotiation with PB producing public policy outcomes, it was the actions outside of PB that captured the attention of the government and induced them to act. Recife’s and Belo Horizonte’s PB programs are therefore best conceptualized as informal governmental decision-making processes, through which government officials, citizens, and CSOs pursue their interests. When the rules were not working, the government changed them. When project implementation was slow, the government took advantage of uncertainty in the process to reward groups that they were aligned with or groups that could potentially embarrass them. The best organized CSOs that were willing to use contentious politics were able to take advantage of the informality of the process to secure the projects that had been previously selected in PB. But this meant that the groups that followed the rules were less likely to secure projects via PB, which indicates that PB has not transformed Belo Horizonte, but is part of a long tradition of elite-mass accomadation. The variation in mayoral support for the delegation of authority is what differentiates Recife and Belo Horizonte from the other six cases. PB participants had to actively engage in contentious politics in order to persuade the governments to fulfill their commitment. This creates a central paradox for these two experiences: Contentious politics by a small number of groups encouraged the government to respond to their demands thereby reinforcing informality and flexibility into the decision-making process. PB was designed to create a public and transparent process through which scarce

34

municipal resources would be distributed. In Recife and Belo Horizonte, this process works for the first stage—policy selection—but does not work for policy implementation. The effect on the deepening of democracy is therefore paradoxical as citizens are rewarded for engaging in a rule-based decision-making body and for moving outside of these rules to secure resources.

Conclusion In this article I laid out the foundations of a framework that will hopefully advance our understanding of the political and policy impact that the burgeoning numbers of participatory experiences may have on efforts to empower citizens, clean up government, and promote social justice in the hopes of deepening democracy. At the heart of the framework is the recognition that we need to analyze the multi-faceted interests of governments, CSOs, and citizens. Governments must be willing to actively participate in a process in which they are delegating binding decision-making authority to citizens. If and when governments are unwilling to delegate real authority to citizens, participatory programs are more likely to be formal shells without much policy or democratic content. It is quite possible that these participatory institutions may emerge as a space for ‘deliberation,’ which may allow citizens to exercise their right to “voice,” but there it is also quite likely that the participants will quickly grow disenchanted with their time spent in deliberative processes rather than in decision-making processes. Under these circumstances, democracy is not deepened. Rather, there is a greater likelihood of extensive disillusionment among the most active members of civil society, which may

35

lead to increased cynicism about the impact that the direct participation of citizens may have on the deepening of democracy. If and when, however, governments are willing to delegate authority, participants not only directly influence specific policy outcomes, but they also alter basic state-society relationships. Governments are more likely to delegate ever greater degrees of binding decision-making authority when government officials believe that the participatory institution will provide the political party in power with specific electoral, mobilization, and governance benefits. Governments delegate authority when there is a sufficiently dense civil society that is comprised of participants who are potential supporters of the government. By delegating authority to potential supporters, the government has the opportunity try to address the most pressing needs of the most active organizations. Governments also delegate authority in order to allow their rank and file party members (or strong sympathizers) the ability to “practice” democracy. The government transfers some basic decision-making authority, thereby allowing the leadership and the rank and file to think of themselves as being quite democratic. It is likely that many of the decisions made by participants coincide with the general interests of the government, but it would be far too reductionist to set this up as a general rule. Governments, especially the case of Porto Alegre, find themselves implementing public policy projects that are not their first-order preference, but were selected by PB participants. Therefore, the deepening of democracy is most likely to occur when government officials’ and CSOs’ interests align. This finding should give us considerable pause about broader claims that the deepening of democracy can be enhanced primarily through the energy and activism of civil society activists.

36

A key issue for citizens involved in participatory institutions is how to closely cooperate with the government, but not fall into a clientelistic or co-opted relationship with the government. Citizens must work closely with government officials in order to schedule meetings, obtain information, prepare technical reports, monitor expenditures, and verify the quality of public policy outputs. Without this close contact and cooperation, participatory programs cannot function well. As argued in the article, the ability of CSOs and participants to avoid co-optation is based on their capacity and willingness to use contentious politics inside and outside of PB. Citizens need to have a range of political tools that can effectively pressure the government to respond to their demands. Often times this involves heated debate within the participatory institutions during which citizens assert their rights and refer extensively to the rules that the government pledged to follow. Participants do not have a posture of meek individuals, but as citizens. CSOs and citizens must also have, at a minimum, the threat of public demonstrations against the government or, in a more active fashion, the willingness to take to the streets to denounce government actions. Governments are more willing to delegate authority and honor their commitments when they face a potentially embarrassing political situation. Therefore, the deepening of democracy is more likely to occur when participants begin to utilize a broad range of practices. If they are unable to simultaneously engage in cooperation and contentious politics, it becomes far less likely that the quality of democracy will be deepened. In sum, understanding the outcomes produced by a burgeoning number of participatory institutions requires that we analyze governments’ willingness to delegate and CSOs’ capacity and willingness to publicly contest the policies and actions of the

37

government who are delegating authority. By analyzing these two factors, we will greatly expand our understanding of the impact that participatory democracy may have in revitalizing older representative democracies and deepening representative democracy in new democracies.

38

Bibliography Abers, Rebecca. 1998. “From Clientelism to Cooperation: Local Government, Participatory Policy, and Civic Organizing in Porto Alegre, Brazil.” Politics and Society 26:511-537. Abers, Rebecca. 2001. Inventing Local Democracy: Grassroots politics in Brazil. Boulder: Westview. Andrade, Edinara. 1996. “As organizações Político Partidárias (subdiretórios) da decade de 70 e a Relação com a estrutura das Atuais associações de Moradores de Blumenau.” Blumeanu: Regional University of Blumenau. Andrade, Edinara. 2000. “Poder Local, Participação Popular, Descentralização e Clientelismo: A Experiênica do Orçamento Participativo de Blumenau.” Blumeanu: Regional University of Blumenau. Avritzer, Leonardo. 2002. Democracy and the Public Space in Latin America. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Avritzer, Leonardo, and Zander Navarro, eds. 2003a. A Inovação Democrática no Brasil: O Orçamento Participativo. São Paulo: Cortez Editores. Baierle, Sergio. 1998. “The Explosion of Citizenship: The Emergence of a New Ethical-Political Principal in Popular Movements in Porto Alegre, Brazil.” In Sonia E. Alvarez, Evelina Dagnino, and Arturo Escobar, eds., Cultures of Politics/Politics of Cultures: Re-Visioning Latin American Social Movements. Boulder: Westview Press. Baiocchi, Gianpaolo. 2001. “Participation, Activism, and Politics: The Porto Alegre Experiment and Deliberative Democratic Theory.” Politics & Society 29:43-72. Baiocchi, Gianpaolo. 2003. Radicals in Power: The Workers’ Party (PT) and experiments in urban democracy in Brazil. New York: Zed Books. Baiocchi, Gianpaolo. 2005. Militants and Citizens: The Politics of Participatory Democracy in Porto Alegre. Stanford: Stanford University Press. Barber, Benjamin. 1984. Strong Democracy: Participatory Politics for a New Age. Berkeley: University of California Press. Brady, Henry and David Collier. 2004. Rethinking Social Inquiry: Diverse Tools, Shared Standards. New York: Rowman and Littlefield Publishers. Daniel, Bruno. 2003. O orçamento participativo local no seu devido lugar: limites colocados por seu desenho institucional e pelo contexto brasileiro—reflexões sobre a experiência de Santo André nos períodos 1989-1992 e 1997-2000. Ph.D. Dissertation. Catholic University of São Paulo. Fedozzi, Luciano. 1998. Orçamento Participativo: Reflexões Sobre a Experiência de Porto Alegre. Porto Alegre: Tomo Editorial.

39

Fung, Archon and Erik Olin Wright. 2003. Deepening Democracy: Institutional Innovations in Empowered Participatory Governance. (London: Verso). Genro, Tarso. 1995. Utopia Possível, 2nd edition. Porto Alegre: Artes e Ofícios. Genro, Tarso. 1997. Porto da Cidadania. Porto Alegre: Artes e Ofícios. Goldfrank, Benjamin. Forthcoming. "The Politics of Deepening Local Democracy: Decentralization, Party Institutionalization, and Participation." Comparative Politics. Goldfrank, Benjamin and Aaron Schneider. 2003. “Restraining the Revolution or Deepening Democracy? The Workers’ Party in Rio Grande do Sul.” In Baiocchi, Gianpaolo. 2003. Radicals in Power: The Workers’ Party (PT) and experiments in urban democracy in Brazil. New York: Zed Books. Guidry, John. 2003. “Not Just Another Labor Party: The Workers’ Party and Democracy in Brazil.” Labor Studies Journal 28:83-108. Heller, Patrick. 2000. “Degrees of Democracy: Some Comparative Lessons from India.” World Politics 52 (4): 484-519. Heller, Patrick. 2001. “Moving the State: The Politics of Democratic Decentralization in Kerala, South Africa, and Porto Alegre.” Politics and Society. 29 (1):131-164. March? Hunter, Wendy. 2004. “From Opposition Movement to Government Party: Growth and Expansion of the Workers’ Party in Brazil.” Paper presented at the 100th annual meeting of the American Political Science Association meeting, Chicago, Illinois. September, 2004. McAdam, Doug, Sidney Tarrow, and Charles Tilly. 2001. Dynamics of Contention. New York: Cambridge University Press. Montero, Alfred P. 2000. “Devolving Democracy? Political Decentralization and the New Brazilian Federalism.” In Peter R. Kingstone and Timothy J. Power, eds., Democratic Braail: Actors, Institutions, and Processes. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press. Nunes, Victor. 1997. Coronelismo, Enxada e Voto: o Município e o Regime Representativo no Brasil, 3rd edition. São Paulo: Editora Nova Fronteira. Nylen, William R. 2002. “Testing the Empowerment Thesis: The Participatory Budget in Belo Horizonte and Betim, Brazil.” Comparative Politics 34:127-145. Nylen, William R. 2003. Participatory Democracy versus Elitist Democracy: Lessons from Brasil. New York: Palgrave Macmillian. Pontual, Pedro de Carvalho. 2000. O Processo Educativo no Orçamento Participativo: Aprendizados dos Atores de Sociedade Civil e do Estado. Doctoral Dissertation. Catholic University of São Paulo. Roberts, Kenneth. 1998. Deepening Democracy? The Modern Left and Social Movements in Chile and Peru. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

40

Rolim, Reidy. 2001. Desafios da Democracia Participativa: O Orçamento Participativo de Blumenau e Seu Impacto Sobre as Associações de Moradores. Master’s Thesis. Regional University of Blumenau, Brazil. Santos, Boaventura de Sousa. 1998. “Participatory Budgeting in Porto Alegre: Toward a Redistributive Democracy.” Politics and Society 26:461-510.

Santos, Boaventura de Sousa. 2005. Democratizing Democracy: Beyond the Liberal Demcoratic Canon. London: Verso. Soares, José Arlindo. 1998. Os Desafios de Gestão Municipal Democrática: Recife. Recife: Cenro Josué de Castro. Souza, Marilete de. 2003. Análise Sócio Política do Orçamento Participativo: Município de Blumenau no Período de 1997 a 2003. Master’s Thesis. Universidade do Vale do Itajaí, Santa Catarina, Brazil. Tarrow, Sidney. 1998. Power in Movement: Social Movements and Contentious Politics, 2nd edition. New York: Cambridge University Press. Teixeira, Ana Cláudia Chaves and Maria do Carmo Albuquerque. 2005. Orçamentos Participativos: projetos politicos, partilha de poder e alcance democrático. Instituto Pólis. Villas-Boas, Renta and Vera Telles. 1995. Poder Local, Participação Popular, Construção da Cidadania. São Paulo: Fórum Nacional de Participação Popular nas Administrações Municipais. Wampler, Brian. 2007 .“Establishing Pluralism in New Democracies: Participatory Democracy in Brazil.” Studies in Comparative International Development. 41:4. Wampler, Brian. 2004. “Expanding Accountability through Participatory Institutions: Mayors, Citizens, and Budgeting in Three Brazilian Municipalities.” Latin American Politics and Society 46:73-100. Wampler, Brian. 2005. “Instituições, Associações e Interesses no Orçamento Participativo do São Paulo.” In Associativismo em São Paulo. Edited by Leonardo Avritzer. (São Paulo: Edusp). Wampler, Brian and Leonardo Avritzer. 2004. Participatory Publics: Civil Society and New Institutions in Democratic Brazil. Comparative Politics 36:291-312. Wampler, Brian and Leonardo Avritzer. 2005. “The spread of Participatory Democracy in Brazil: From Radical Democracy to Good Government.” Journal of Latin American Urban Studies. V7: 37-52

41

Endnotes

1

According to Brazilian law, no “new capital investment” projects (focus of most

PB programs) included in the budget have to be implemented; they are legally classified as discretionary funding. Federal law 4.320. April 3, 1964. 2

In 1997, the PT government in Belem adopted a PB program. The government was re-

elected in 2000, but opted to implement an alternative participatory model in 2001. 3

Revista de COMPOR. Prefeitura de Ipatinga, MG. 1999. PP 1-4.

4

“Numero de participantes: Plenarias regionais do Orcamento Participativo.” Municipal

Government of Porto Alegre. June 7th, 2004. 5

The survey was initially conducted by the Instituto Ethos between November 25

and December 10. 2003 in eight municipalities. Survey methodology: This survey is a representative sample of PB delegates rather than a random survey of PB delegates. The distribution among the different municipalities was: Porto Alegre (60), Ipatinga (60), Belo Horizonte (60), Santo Andre (60), São Paulo (300), Recife (60), Blumenau (60),and Rio Claro (30). In order to generate an appropriate phone list of current delegates, the author contacted each municipal government to obtain the names and phone numbers of individuals who were serving as PB delegates in 2003. Individuals were then randomly selected. 6

Interview with Vice-Mayor Inácio da Silva Mafra. January 22, 2004. Interview with

City Council Member Jean Klunderman. January 12, 2004. 7

“Orçamento Participativo: A vontade do povo via mostrar a sua força.” 2002.

Prefeitura Municipal de Blumenau.; “Prestação de Contas do Orçamento Participativo.

42

1999. Prefeitura Municipal de Blumenau. Analysis of the annul budget and final report on spending, 1997-2002. 8

“Orçamento Participativo: Democratizando o Dinheiro Público.” Prefeitura

Municipal de Rio Claro.” 2002; “Venha Participar do Planejamento de Rio Claro” Prefeitura Municipal de Rio Claro.” 2001. 9

Interview with Teresa Santos, 10/14/2003. Santo Andre, Brazil.

10

Interview with PB Delegate Fatima from Capella de Soccoro, November 11,

2003. Sao Paulo, Brazil.

43