Economic growth and the quantity and quality of entrepreneurship

9 downloads 103 Views 213KB Size Report
They almost certainly regret this decision now since J. K Rowling's ... 1 In 2008 J.K. Rowling was the only billionaire author on Forbes' list among the world ...
         

UNGA FORSKARPRISET 2009

Economic growth and the quantity and quality of entrepreneurship    

Kristina Nyström

Department of Transport and Economics The Royal Institute of Technology Drottning Kristinas väg 30 SE-100 44 Stockholm Sweden and The Ratio Institute P.O. Box 3203 SE-103 64 Stockholm Sweden E-mail: [email protected]

     

         

1. Introduction

In  recent  years,  researchers  and  policy  makers  has  devoted  a  lot  of  attention  to  the  role   of  entrepreneurship  for  economic  growth.  Many  policymakers  believe  that  improved   levels  of  entrepreneurship  are  the  salvation  for  economies  struggling  with  declining   economic  growth  rates  and  employment  rates.  To  what  extend  does  this  belief  rely  on   solid  empirical  evidence  on  the  relationship  between  entrepreneurship  and  growth?  Is   it  true  that  entrepreneurship  unambiguously  can  be  claimed  to  improve  economic   growth?  In  fact,  previous  empirical  findings  on  the  relationship  between   entrepreneurship  and  growth  give  an  in  some  aspects  scattered  picture.  A  recent   review  of  the  empirical  evidence  by  van  Praag  and  Versloot  (2007),  conclude  that   entrepreneurs  are  important  to  employment  growth  and  productivity.    On  the  other   hand,  Henrekson  and  Stenkula  (2007)  and  Nyström  (2008),  conclude  that  the  empirical   evidence  regarding,  in  particular,  the  role  of  entrepreneurship  for  employment  growth   is  unclear  or  even  contradictory.    For  the  firm  level  Shane  (2009)  even  concludes  that   ”the  typical  start-­‐up  is  not  innovative,  creates  few  jobs  and  generates  little  wealth”   (Shane,  p.  141).         Based  on  the  empirical  evidence  Shane  (2009)  argues  that  policy  aimed  at  stimulating   the  “quantity”  of  entrepreneurship  can  be  questioned.  An  increased  focus  on  the   “quality”  of  new  firm  start-­‐ups  is  called  for.  In  particular,  a  small  number  of  high  growth   firms  (gazelles)  has  been  identified  as  “high  quality  entrepreneurship”  due  to  their   potential  to  generate  jobs  (see  e.g.  Henrekson  and  Johansson,  2009).  Does  this  imply   that  the  lions  part  of  all  new  firms  started  around  the  world  are  of  no  importance  to  the   economy?  In  this  essay  I  will  argue  that  even  if  a  small  amount  of  high  quality   entrepreneurs  seem  to  be  of  particular  importance  for  generating  employment  growth,   the  importance  of  a  certain  quantity  of  entrepreneurs  should  not  be  neglected.  The   entrepreneurial  firms  are  crucial  for  the  dynamic  selection  mechanism  in  the  economy.   Hence,  they  are  influential  even  though  most  of  them  are  not  very  successful,   innovative  and  very  few  turn  out  to  be  gazelles.  In  this  essay,  I  will  firstly  briefly  review   the  empirical  evidence  on  the  role  of  entrepreneurship  in  a  dynamic  perspective.  The   review  will  focus  on  three  aspects  of  economic  growth,  the  effect  on  productivity,   employment,  and  aggregate  economic  growth.  1  What  is  the  empirical  evidence  and   what  are  the  policy  implications?  Such  a  review  will  help  us  to  get  a  deeper   understanding  of  the,  in  some  aspects,  inconclusive  empirical  evidence  on  the  

                                                                                                            1

A more detailed review can be found in Nyström (2008)

 

2  

          relationship  between  entrepreneurship  and  economic  growth.  Furthermore,  it  will  help   us  to  identify  some  important  areas  for  future  research  in  the  entrepreneurship  field.  

2. Empirical evidence on the relationship between entrepreneurship and growth ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND PRODUCTIVITY The  empirical  literature  that  studies  the  role  of  entrepreneurship  for  productivity   distinguishes  between  the  productivity  effect  of  internal  re-­‐allocation  and  external  re-­‐ allocation.  Internal  re-­‐allocation  refers  to  the  productivity  contribution  from  innovation   or  re-­‐organization  in  existing  firms.  External  re-­‐allocation  refer  to  contribution  to   productivity  induced  by  the  selection  mechanisms  associated  with  entry  of  more   productive  firms,  exit  of  less  productive  firms  and  productivity  gains  due  to  decreases  or   increases  of  incumbent  firms  market  shares.         Several studies find that market selection mechanism contributes to a majority of the productivity growth. (See for example the studies by Disney et al., 2003; Hedén, 2005; Baldwin and Gu, 2006) and Foster et al., 2006.) Other researchers are less convinced about the positive relationship between productivity and external re-allocation. Scarpetta et al. (2002) find that a large share of the increase in labor productivity is due to internal re-allocation. Andersson (2006) shows that for the period 1997–2003 90 percent of labor productivity growth in Sweden was due to internal re-allocation. However, what these studies have in common is that they study a quite short period (only five years). Based on an extensive overview of the empirical results regarding importance of firm dynamics for productivity growth Ahn (2001) conclude that in the long-run new firms that survive are important to productivity growth. However, in the short run the effect of new firm formation on productivity may be even be negative. Furthermore, firm dynamics seem to be more important for productivity growth in service sectors compared to manufacturing sectors. In summary, there is convincing evidence of a long-run positive effect of new firm formation (and exit) on productivity growth.

ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND EMPLOYMENT GROWTH Quite  a  few  authors  have  tried  so  summarize  the  empirical  results  on  the  relationship   between  entrepreneurship  and  employment  growth.  (See  for  example  van  Praag  and   Versloot,  2007,  Henrekson  and  Stenkula,  2007  and  Nyström,  2008  for  recent   summaries).  As  previously  mentioned  their  conclusions  are  sometimes  contradictory.   How  should  we  interpret  these  empirical  results?  It  has  been  argued  that  a  dynamic    

3  

          perspective  needs  to  be  applied  in  order  to  reconcile  the  full  effects  of   entrepreneurship  on  employment  growth.  Fritsch  and  Mueller  (2004)  argue  that  the   employment  effects  of  new  firm  formation  occur  in  three  steps.  Firstly,  a  direct   employment  effect,  which  is,  associated  a  new  firm  entering  the  market  and  employing   people.  This  effect  induces  a  positive  employment  effect.  Secondly,  the  selection   mechanisms  set  in,  which  might  cause  a  negative  employment  effect.  The  selection   mechanism  occurs  due  to  that  increased  competition  may  force  some  of  the  incumbent   firms  to  close  down.  In  addition,  we  know  that  most  of  the  new  firms  do  not  survive.   Finally,  and  perhaps  the  most  important  according  to  Fritsch  and  Mueller  (2004)  indirect   supply-­‐side  effects  sets  in.  The  indirect  effects  refers  to  that  we  assume  that  these  new   firms  influence  already  incumbent  firms.  If  a  new  firm  brings  an  innovation  to  the   market  it  may  cause  improvements  in  production  in  other  firms  or  might  stimulate   further  innovations,  which  further  increases  efficiency.  Furthermore,  resources  will  be   re-­‐allocated  to  other  and  expanding  markets.  However,  this  increased  efficiency  and   increased  competition  does  not  necessarily  imply  an  increase  in  employment.   Nevertheless,  Fritsch  and  Mueller  (2004)  find  that  the  indirect  employment  effects  of   new  firm  formation  might  be  positive  and  actually  be  more  important  than  the  direct   employment  effects.       The  dynamic  process  described  above  is  a  long-­‐term  process  and  it  may  take  up  to  ten   years  until  the  positive  employment  effect  can  be  observed  (Fritsch,  2008).  How  the   dynamics  related  to  these  indirect  supply  side  effects  occurs  more  explicitly  is   something  that  is  yet  quite  vague.  How  does  this  re-­‐allocation  of,  for  example,  labor   actually  take  place?  This  is  clearly  a  process  future  research  need  to  study  closer.   Recently,  matched  firm-­‐employees  datasets  has  become  available  in  some  countries.   These  databases  makes  it  possible  to  examine  the  re-­‐allocation  processes  by  means  of   following  the  employment  history  of  individuals  employed  in  new  expanding,   contracting  and  exiting  firms.       Another  important  finding  in  the  empirical  literature  on  the  relationship  between   entrepreneurship  and  employment  growth  is  that  the  employment  effect  varies   substantially  across  time  and  space.  Why  do  we  find  a  negative  effect  of   entrepreneurship  on  employment  growth  in  certain  industries  and  regions?  Two  main   hypotheses  have  been  put  forward.  One  hypothesis  is  the  imperfect  selection   mechanism  hypothesis,  which  implies  that  for  some  reason  firms  with  low  productivity   remain  on  the  market  while  high  productivity  firm  exit.      The  fastest  growing  industries   in  terms  of  employment  growth  is,  for  example,  characterized  by  both  high  entry  and   exit  rates  (Nyström  ,  2009).  Hence,  market  turbulence  is  important  for  the  selection   mechanism  to  work  properly.  In  some  cases  government  interventions  is  one   explanation  to  why  these  selection  mechanisms  do  not  seem  to  work  properly  (see  e.g.  

 

4  

          Fritsch  and  Schroeter,  2009).  A  second  explanation  put  forward  is  the  overcrowding   hypothesis  which  imply  that  if  a  particular  market  has  reached  certain  threshold   additional  entry  has  no  or  even  negative  effect  employment  effects.  Why  do   entrepreneur  still  try  to  enter  such  industries?  If  barriers  to  entry  are  low  and   entrepreneurs  are  overconfident  regarding  their  chances  of  success  overcrowding  may   be  a  plausible  hypothesis.  Furthermore,  public  subsidies  aimed  at  stimulating   entrepreneurship  might  cause  such  overcrowding  (Fritsch  and  Schroeter,  2009).    Hence,   the  policy  lesson  that  can  be  made  is  that  public  policy  that  interfere  with  market   selections  mechanisms  might  not  be  beneficial  for  the  economy  in  the  long  run   perspective.    

ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND AGGREGATE ECONOMIC GROWTH Due  to  the  lack  of  comparable  cross-­‐country  data  on  entrepreneurship,  there  are  few   studies  on  the  relationship  between  entrepreneurship  and  economic  performance  at   the  country  level  available  (Carree  and  Thurik,  2003).  Most  studies  available  are  based   on  self-­‐employment  as  a  measure  of  entrepreneurship.  More  recently,  data  from  the   Global  Entrepreneurship  Monitor      (GEM)  has  been  used.  There  is  clearly  a  need  of   comparable  cross-­‐country  data  on,  in  particular,  new  firm  formation.  Such  data  would   make  it  possible  for  researchers  to  learn  more  about  how  different  institutional  settings   may  influence  the  quantity  and  quality  of  entrepreneurship.       The  empirical  evidence  on  the  relationship  between  entrepreneurship  and  aggregate   economic  growth  so  far  provide  somewhat  ambiguous  results.  Nevertheless,  most  of   the  studies  show  results  that  imply  that  entrepreneurship  have  positive  effects  on   aggregate  economic  growth.  Studies  that  find  a  positive  relationship  between   entrepreneurship  and  economic  growth  are,  for  example,  Klapper  et  al.  (2007)  and  Acs   et  al.  (2004).  Again,  these  studies  show  that  there  seem  to  be  a  substantial  time  lag   before  the  positive  effect  can  be  observed  (see  e.g.  Reynolds  et  al.,  2004  and    Carree,   and  Thurik,  2008).     Carree  et  al.  (2002)  raise  the  question  whether  there  is  an  ‘equilibrium’  level  with   respect  to  the  quantity  of  entrepreneurship  in  a  country.  The  equilibrium  level  of   entrepreneurship  is  defined  with  regard  to  the  deployment  stage  of  each  country.  In   their  empirical  study,  they  find  that  entrepreneurship  below  as  well  as  above  the   ‘equilibrium’  level  have  negative  consequences  for  aggregate  economic  growth.  Van   Stel  et  al.  (2005)  find  that  in  countries,  which  can  be  regarded  as  relatively  rich,  there  is   a  positive  relationship  between  entrepreneurship  and  economic  growth,  while  it  is  was   negative  in  less  developed  countries.  An  extended  version  of  Carree  (2002)  again  finds   that  entrepreneurship  levels  below  the  equilibrium  level  have  a  negative  effect  on  

 

5  

          growth.  However,  in  this  study  they  do  not  find  any  negative  effect  of  deviations  above   the  equilibrium  level  of  entrepreneurship  (Carree  et  al.  2007).  In  summary,  the  quantity   of  entrepreneurship  increase  economic  growth  at  least  up  to  a  certain  level.     Some  studies  try  to  distinguish  between  qualitative  aspects  of  different  types  of   entrepreneurship  i.e  assuming  that  they  have  different  potential  for  creating  economic   growth.  Wong  et  al.  (2005)  define  high  growth  potential  entrepreneurs  using  the   following  characteristics:  who  have  employment  growth  potential,  have  effect  on  the   market,  have  a  global  customer  base  and  use  new  technology.  They  find  that  high   growth  potential  entrepreneurship  does  have  a  positive  effect  on  economic  growth.   Contrary  to  what  might  be  expected  Reynolds  et  al.  (2004)  find  that  the  relationship   between  opportunity-­‐based  entrepreneurship  and  growth  seems  to  decrease  over  time   while  the  relationship  between  necessity-­‐based1  entrepreneurship  and  growth  tends  to   increase  over  time.    

3. Conclusions and policy implications

This  essay  has  briefly  reviewed  the  empirical  evidence  on  the  relationship  between   entrepreneurship  and  economic  growth  in  terms  of  productivity,  employment  growth   and  aggregate  economic  growth.  Most  empirical  evidence  show  that  entrepreneurship   has  an  important  role  for  generating  economic  growth  in  a  long  run  perspective.   However,  the  employment  effects  of  entrepreneurship  may  vary  significantly  across   time  and  space.  Hence,  entrepreneurship  seems  to  be  a  necessary  but  not  sufficient   condition  for  economic  growth.     How should then policy makers respond to this evidence? As previously mentioned policy makers have started to show an increasing interest in trying to identify “high quality entrepreneurs”. Shane, (2009) argue that government officials will have a low probability of “picking the winners”. Instead, he proposes that they should avoid supporting firms with low probability of generating jobs and decrease the incentives of starting such jobs, i.e. an “avoiding the “losers” strategy. Identifying, “losers” is equally or even more difficult than to pick winners. In fact, we can expect it to be much more difficult. There are quite a lot of empirical research on survivors and successful entrepreneurs to lean on. The research area devoted to firm exit is much less explored. Strategies aimed at either “picking winners” and “avoiding losers” will be difficult and dangerous strategies to implement. Some additional examples will illustrate this point. Gazelles are often identified as a group of high quality entrepreneurs. Contrary to what

                                                                                                            1  Necessity-based entrepreneurship refers to entrepreneurship initiated by lack of other employment opportunities such as for example unemployment.  

 

6  

          most of us expect the high technology firms are not overrepresented among gazelles. Instead young, small and firms in the service sector are overrepresented among gazelles (Henrekson and Johansson, 2009). Only very few gazelles manage to show continued growth and the strategies implemented that results in a gazelle are constantly changing (Parker, Storey and Witteloostuijn, 2005). With access to the blunt tools available to identify projects that should be avoided, most of us would hesitate to invest in a project initialized by an, at the time, recently divorced, unemployed, single-mother, who wants to publish a children’s book with a ten year old magician as the main character. In fact, many publishers turned the manuscript down, probably based on their strategies to avoid “investing in losers”. They almost certainly regret this decision now since J. K Rowling’s book project about Harry Potter turned out to be a tremendous success story.1 In fact, a government institution (The Scottish Arts council) managed to identify this project as a “winner” since they provided her with a grant in order for her to finish the first book on Harry Potter. In summary we can find examples of situations were government officials manage to “pick winners” among losers, as well as they would sometimes “pick losers” out of winners. The important point is that it would be dangerous to expect government officials to have better possibilities than customers, venture capitalist or business angels to judge which entrepreneurial projects that are viable. What  is  then  the  role  of  public  policy?  Baumol  (1990)  argues  strongly  for  his  hypothesis   that  the  total  amount  of  entrepreneurs  in  a  society  may  vary  but  that  the  allocation   between  productive,  unproductive  an  even  destructive  entrepreneurship  vary  much   more.  The  institutional  environment,  i.e  “rules  of  the  game“,  ultimately  determine  if   entrepreneurs  will  engage  in  productive  or  unproductive  activities.  Hence  the  challenge   for  policy  makers  is  to  provide  a  good  institutional  environment  which  re-­‐allocates   entrepreneurs  towards  productive  entrepreneurship,  instead  of  unproductive  or   destructive  entrepreneurship.2         In  the  search  for  qualitative  entrepreneurship,  institutions  and  the  quantity  of   entrepreneurship  are  not  unimportant.    Not  all  teams  playing  in  the  soccer  World  Cup   have  the  same  odds  to  become  champions.  Most  years,  countries  like  Brazil.  Argentina,   France  and  Italy  are  the  teams  playing  the  finals.  In  the  short  run,  it  would  probably  be   more  efficient  (but  extremely  boring)  to  just  let  these  four  teams  play  the  World  Cup.   However,  in  the  end  other  teams  would  not  make  any  efforts  to  create  a  good  team.   Such  a  strategy  will  have  devastating  effects  on  the  quality  of  soccer  games  played  all                                                                                                               1

In 2008 J.K. Rowling was the only billionaire author on Forbes’ list among the world richest (Thompson,

2008). 2

See Boettke and Coyne, (2009) for a recent review of the role of institutions for entrepreneurial activities.

 

7  

          over  the  world.  Instead,  we  set  up  rules  that  give  all  countries  the  opportunity  to  qualify   for  the  World  Cup.  When  the  whistle  blows,  the  rules  of  the  game  are  equal  to  all   players.  Under  such  circumstances,  the  rules  of  the  game  will  create  incentives  to   improvement  in  all  teams.  Occasionally  surprises  happen  and  even  the  Swedish  soccer   team  might  end  up  playing  the  finals.        

References

Acs,  Z.J.  D.  B.  Audretsch,  P.  Braunerhjelm    and    B.  Carlsson  (2004),  The  Knowledge  Filter     and  Entrepreneurship  in  Endogenous  Growth,  Discussion  paper  on     Entrepreneurship,  growth  and  Public  Policy  Nr  0805,  Max  Planck  Institute,  Jena   Ahn,  S.  (2001),  Firm  Dynamics  and  Productivity  Growth:  A  Review  of  Micro  Evidence     from  OECD  Countries  OECD  Economics  department  Working  Paper  NO.  297,  OECD,   Paris.   Andersson,  L-­‐F.  (2006),  Företagsdynamik  och  tillväxt,  En  kartläggning  och  analys  av     företagsdynamik  och  arbetsproduktivitetstillväxt  i  Sverige.    (Firm  Dynamics  and   growth),  ITPS  report    A2006:016,  Swedish  Institute  for  Growth  Policy  Studies,   Östersund.   Baldwin,  J.R.  and  W.  Gu  (2006),  Competition,  Firm  Turnover  and  Productivity  Growth,     Research  Paper  Economic  Analysis,  Research  Paper  Series,  Statistics  Canada   Baumol,  W.  J.  (1990),  Entrepreneurship:  Productive,  Unproductive  and  Destructive,     Journal  of  Political  Economy,  98,  893-­‐921   Boettke,  P.  J.  and  C.  J.  Coyne,  (2009)  Context  matters:  institutions  and     Entrepreneurship,  Foundations  and  trends  in  Entrepreneurship,  Vol  5.  3:135-­‐209.   Carree,  M.,  A.  van  Stel,  A.R.  Thurik  and  S.  Wennekers  (2002),  Economic  Development     and  Business  Ownership:  An  Analysis  Using  Data  of  23  OECD  Countries  in  the  Period   1976-­‐1996,  Small  Business  Economics,  19,  271-­‐290   Carree,  M.  and  A.  R.  Thurik  (2008),  The  Lag  Structure  of  the  Impact  of  Business     Ownership  on  Economic  Growth  in  OECD  Countries,  Small  Business  Economics,  30,   1:101-­‐110,  January.   Disney,  R,  J.  Haskel  and  Y.  Heden  (2003),  Restructuring  and  Productivity  Growth  in  UK     Manufacturing,  Economic  Journal  113,  666-­‐694   Foster,  L.,  J.C.  Haltiwanger  and  C.  J.  Krizan  (2006),  Market  Selection,  Reallocation,  and     Restructuring  in  the  U.  S  Retail  Trade  Sector  in  the  1990s,  The  Review  of  Economics   and  Statistics  88,  748-­‐758   Fritsch,  M.  (2008),  How  Does  Business  Formation  Affect  Regional  Development?     Introduction  to  the  Special  Issue,  Small  Business  Economics,  30,  1-­‐14   Fritsch,  M.  and  P.  Mueller  (2004),  Effects  of  Business  Formation  on  Regional    

 

8  

          Development  over  Time,  Regional  Studies,  38,  961-­‐975   Fritsch  M.  and  A.  Schroeter  (2009)  Are  More  Start-­‐ups  Really  Better?  Quantity  and     Quality  of  new  Businesses  and  Their  Effect  on  regional  developmet  jena  Economic   research  Papers  2009-­‐070.   Hedén,  Y.  (2005),  Productivity,  Upskilling,  Restructuring,  Entry  and  Exit:  Evidence  from     the  UK  and  Swedish  Micro  Data,  University  of  London   Henrekson,  M.  and  M.  Stenkula  (2007),  Entreprenörskap,  (Entrepreneurship)  SNS,     Stockholm   Henrekson  M.    and  D.  Johansson,  (2009)    Gazelles  as  job  creators:  a  survey  and     interpretation  of  the  Evidence,  Small  Business  Economics,  (forthcoming)   Klapper,  L.,  R.  Amit,  M.E.  Guillén  &  J.M.  Quesada  (2007),  Entrepreneurship  and  New     Firm  Formation  Across  Countries,  Policy  Research  Working  paper  4313,  The  World   Bank   Nyström  K.  (2008)    Is  Entrepreneurship  the  Salvation  for  Enhanced  Economic  Growth?     CESIS  Working  Paper  Series  No.  143,  CESIS,  Royal  Institute  of  Technology,  Stockholm.   Nyström  K.  (2009)  “Entry,  Market  Turbulence  and  Industry  Employment  Growth”,     Empirica,  36  (3)  293-­‐308.   Parker  S.  C.  ,  Storey  D.  J.  and  A  van  Witteloostuijn,  (2005)  What  Happens  to  Gazelles?     The  Importance  of  dynamic  Management  Strategy,  Report  Entrepreneurship   Research  series  University  of  Durham.   Reynolds,  P.D.,  W.D.  Bygrave  and  E.  Autio  (2004),  Global  Entrepreneurship  Monitor:     2003  Executive  Report,  Babson  College,  Babson  Park,  MA   Scarpetta,  S.,  P.  Hemmings,  T.  Tressel,  and  J.  Woo  (2002),  The  Role  of  Policy  and     Institutions  for  Productivity  and  Firm  Dynamics  Evidence  from  Micro  and  Industry   Data,  OECD  Economics  Department  Working  paper  no.  329,  OECD,  Paris    Shane,  S,  (2009)  Why  encouraging  more  people  to  become  entrepreneurs  is  a  bad     policy,  Small  Business  Economics,  33  141-­‐149.   Thompson  ,  S.  (2008)  Business  big  shot:  Harry  potter  author  J.  K.  Rowling,    The  Times,       April  2.  2009     van  Praag,  M.C.    and    P.H.  Versloot  (2007),  What  is  the  Value  of  Entrepreneurship?  A     Review  of  Recent  Research,  Small  Business  Economics,  29,  351-­‐382,     van  Stel  A,  M.  Carree  and  R.  Thurik  (2005),  The  Effect  of  Entrepreneurial  Activity  on     National  Income  Growth,  Small  Business  Economics,  24,  311-­‐321   Wong  P.K.,  Y.P.  Ho  and  E.  Autio  (2005),  Entrepreneurship,  Innovation,  and  Economic     Growth:  Evidence  from  GEM  Data,  Small  Business  Economics,  24,  335-­‐350  

 

9